Liberty Street Economics

« | Main | »

February 12, 2020

Reading the Tea Leaves of the U.S. Business Cycle—Part Two

Reading the Tea Leaves of the U.S. Business Cycle—Part Two


In our previous post, we presented evidence suggesting that labor market indicators provide the most reliable information for dating the U.S. business cycle. In this post, we further develop the case. In fact, the unemployment rate has provided an almost perfect record of distinguishing the beginning of recessions in the post-war U.S. economy. We also show that using more granular labor market data, such as by region or industry, also provides valuable information about the state of the business cycle.


The most natural starting point for employing labor market variables is the unemployment rate. It has advantages of being timely and only minimally revised; however, the unemployment rate is typically not used for business cycle dating by the NBER business cycle dating committee (BCDC). As the committee has explained, the metric is both a leading and lagging indicator:

“[The BCDC] considers economic activity, which grows along an upward trend. As a result, the unemployment rate often rises before the peak of economic activity, when activity is still rising but below its normal trend rate of increase. Thus, the unemployment rate is often a leading indicator of the business-cycle peak. […] On the other hand, the unemployment rate often continues to rise after activity has reached its trough. In this respect, the unemployment rate is a lagging indicator.”

The top panel of the chart below shows the unemployment rate (blue line) along with the NBER recessions (blue shading) and the recessions implied by the Bry-Boschan (BB) algorithm (pink shading) based on current unemployment rate data (a methodology described in depth in our companion post). The BB algorithm applied to the unemployment rate dates the peaks earlier and troughs later as compared to NBER recessions (top panel). The bottom panel reproduces this dating exercise for each vintage unemployment series, with the y-axis representing the years available. If we look horizontally for a chosen vintage, red (gray) shading indicates periods of recession (expansion) based on the BB algorithm and those vintage data. We observe a similar encompassing of the NBER recessions using real-time data. Interestingly, the BB algorithm detects a cycle around the mid-1960s that was not identified by the BCDC. Milton Friedman (Friedman 1970) argued that this period should have been designated a recession.

Reading the Tea Leaves of the U.S. Business Cycle—Part One

Our analysis suggests that business cycle dating using the unemployment rate may be better implemented using “threshold rules.” A threshold rule exploits the empirical regularity that the unemployment rate tends to either rise or fall—and only very rarely moves sideways (as evident in the top panel of the chart above). Thus, once it rises “enough” we observe a continued sharp increase which has historically coincided with U.S. recessions.

Threshold rules for the unemployment rate have been used by private-sector forecasters and policymakers for many years (see, for example, the 30-basis-point thresholds advocated by former New York Fed President Dudley in 2001, former Chair Bernanke in 2006, or former Richmond Fed President Lacker in 2008). This idea has been formalized in Stock and Watson (2010), Hatzius and Stehn (2012), and Sahm (2019). Our approach follows Hatzius and Stehn (2012).

We first filter the (unrounded) unemployment rate by taking three-month moving averages to reduce noise, and then subtract the most recent local minimum (prior twelve-months) from the current three-month moving average. The top panel of the chart below shows the evolution of this measure against NBER-dated recessions. The threshold line shows a value of 35 basis points as advocated by Hatzius and Stehn (2012). As it can be seen, NBER-dated peaks are well-proxied by times when the filtered unemployment rate crosses the 35-basis-point threshold from below. This is further illustrated in the middle panel that overlays threshold-based recession dating on the NBER-dating. The threshold approach is an improvement relative to the BB rule (as is obvious in a comparison to the top panel of the chart above). Since the unemployment rate is not revised much, this rule is reliable and stable even in real time (see the bottom panel of chart below).

Reading the Tea Leaves of the U.S. Business Cycle—Part One

At first glance, the threshold rule may appear ad hoc—especially the choice of cutoff. Instead we argue that it is quite reasonable. In fact, Okun’s law provides a neat reconciliation of the threshold rule on unemployment and the local maxima in real GDP. The “difference version” of Okun’s law is: Δyt = kcΔut where Δyt is real GDP growth, Δut is the change in the unemployment rate and k and c are positive numbers; thus, an increase in the unemployment rate is associated with a decline in output only if Δut >kc. This explains why it is important to move to a threshold rule for dating with the unemployment rate. Using estimated values of k and c based on Okun’s law over our sample, we obtain a threshold value of around 50 basis points—very close to the choice of Hatzius and Stehn (2012).

Although the aggregate unemployment rate performs impressively based on the results in our first post, it is natural to investigate whether cross-sectional information can further refine the signal from the labor market. We first explore the signal coming from different industries in the economy. We use the cross section of private payrolls from the Establishment Survey across seventy-seven industries (defined by their three-digit NAICS codes). We apply the BB algorithm to each of these payroll series and calculate the cross-sectional share of industries in contraction. The blue line in the interactive chart below shows the time series based on the full sample; the gold line shows the real-time value for each month based on a recursive application of the BB algorithm using real-time data series. Even with real-time data, we observe a sharp rise leading into the recession of the share of industries in recession. Currently, the measure is at levels similar to the 2015-16 period, and below levels observed leading into the previous recession.

The heatmap in the bottom panel of the chart below shows in each row industry payroll employment grouped by the respective two-digit NAICS code, with red pixels identifying months of contraction based on the BB algorithm. The most informative sector for business cycle fluctuations appears to be the “other services,” along with wholesale and retail trade. In contrast, the manufacturing sector experiences frequent and persistent cycles that are not associated with aggregate fluctuations. This observation paired with our discussion of the divergence between manufacturing and the broader economy in the 2014-16 period from our previous post
reinforces our argument that manufacturing data may be overly relied upon for assessing the state of the business cycle.

We may also investigate the geographic variation of local labor markets. As noted for the national unemployment rate, the threshold approach performs better than the BB algorithm at capturing the turning points in economic fluctuations. Because threshold levels may differ across states, we estimate a two-state threshold regression model as in
Koop and Potter (1999),
where the threshold variable is measured by the distance of the unemployment rate from its recent trough or from its recent peak if the peak occurs after a trough. This threshold generalizes the concept applied to the aggregate unemployment rate to not only economic peaks but also troughs. Each state’s threshold is then estimated from the data.

The blue line in the chart below shows the share of state unemployment rates which have crossed each state’s estimated threshold based on the current series of state unemployment data; the gold line shows the value for each month based on an out-of-sample exercise using real-time data and recursive estimation. The real-time series is only modestly noisier than the full sample and, thus, provides a similar signal. The share is very informative about onsets of recessions and, based on current data, is at low levels.



The heatmap in the bottom panel of the chart shows in rows each state unemployment rate with red pixels identifying months of the state unemployment above the threshold. Recessions are times of widespread increases in regional unemployment rates, which only a few states appear to be experiencing at the moment.


Crump_richard
Richard Crump is a vice president in the Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s Research and Statistics Group.

Domenico Giannone was formerly an assistant vice president in the Bank’s Research and Statistics Group. This work was completed while he was an employee.

Lucca_david
David Lucca is an assistant vice president in the Bank’s Research and Statistics Group.


DisclaimerThe views expressed in this post are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the authors.

Comments

Feed You can follow this conversation by subscribing to the comment feed for this post.

Good morning, very interesting case and conclusions. I just wonder if the threshold should not be adjusted by the level of unemployment (i.e., if a 50 bp threshold when unemployment rate is at 3.50% is the same when unemployment is at 10%). Thanks.

The comments to this entry are closed.

About the Blog

Liberty Street Economics features insight and analysis from New York Fed economists working at the intersection of research and policy. Launched in 2011, the blog takes its name from the Bank’s headquarters at 33 Liberty Street in Manhattan’s Financial District.

The editors are Michael Fleming, Andrew Haughwout, Thomas Klitgaard, and Asani Sarkar, all economists in the Bank’s Research Group.

Liberty Street Economics does not publish new posts during the blackout periods surrounding Federal Open Market Committee meetings.

The views expressed are those of the authors, and do not necessarily reflect the position of the New York Fed or the Federal Reserve System.

Economic Research Tracker

Image of NYFED Economic Research Tracker Icon Liberty Street Economics is available on the iPhone® and iPad® and can be customized by economic research topic or economist.

Economic Inequality

image of inequality icons for the Economic Inequality: A Research Series

This ongoing Liberty Street Economics series analyzes disparities in economic and policy outcomes by race, gender, age, region, income, and other factors.

Most Read this Year

Comment Guidelines

 

We encourage your comments and queries on our posts and will publish them (below the post) subject to the following guidelines:

Please be brief: Comments are limited to 1,500 characters.

Please be aware: Comments submitted shortly before or during the FOMC blackout may not be published until after the blackout.

Please be relevant: Comments are moderated and will not appear until they have been reviewed to ensure that they are substantive and clearly related to the topic of the post.

Please be respectful: We reserve the right not to post any comment, and will not post comments that are abusive, harassing, obscene, or commercial in nature. No notice will be given regarding whether a submission will or will
not be posted.‎

Comments with links: Please do not include any links in your comment, even if you feel the links will contribute to the discussion. Comments with links will not be posted.

Send Us Feedback

Disclosure Policy

The LSE editors ask authors submitting a post to the blog to confirm that they have no conflicts of interest as defined by the American Economic Association in its Disclosure Policy. If an author has sources of financial support or other interests that could be perceived as influencing the research presented in the post, we disclose that fact in a statement prepared by the author and appended to the author information at the end of the post. If the author has no such interests to disclose, no statement is provided. Note, however, that we do indicate in all cases if a data vendor or other party has a right to review a post.

Archives